Thursday, July 7, 2016

The Experience of West Bengal, India

Participatory Management of Sundarbans and The Experience of West Bengal, India
By Dr.Fourkan Ali

Sundarbans is one of the last tropical deltaic mangrove forests in Asia, the rest having convened to rice agriculture. A rare and endangered ecological system, the deltaic mangrove wetland forest of the Sundarbans bridges Bangladesh and India ir-r the southwest, bordering the Bay of Bengal. Once a vast expanse of luxuriant mangrove forest, it has been reduced over the years to a large extent due to land reclamation for agriculture, settlements and ever growing biotic pressure on forest products.

Till recent times, the landscape of the Sundarbans was a product of two countervailing forces: conversion of wetland forests to cropland versus sequestration of forests in reserves to be managed by the Forest Department (FD) for long-term sustained yield of wood products. During the colonial period, state reclamation efforts were encouraged through landlords by increasingly favorable state policies (land grants, tax incentives, cadastral surveys, and eventually colonization projects and subsidized irrigation). These policies were designed by revenue officials to maximize the rate of transformation of wetland forest to taxable agricultural land. In the late 19th century as the rate of agricultural conversion increased, the colonial FD sought to preserve the remaining Sundarbans forest by giving them legal status as Reserve Forest. They were managed to provide a sustainable supply of timber and fuel-wood for the growing population of southern Bengal. Today the supplies of some economically valuable tree species have been depleted and some mammals are locally extinct.

Obviously the question of management comes in a big way. Conventional state management is questioned in many countries, because of declining productivity of state forests, growing imbalance between supply and demand of forest products, declining tree cover in state forests, and rising conflicts between FD staff and local communities. Some experts argue that the main cause of deforestation is the inability of forest owners/managers to exclude various user groups from the resources which in theory are under a well-defined r property regime. Therefore, the problem is not with the property regime as such, but with its enforcement. This is relevant particularly in countries of the sub-continent, where forest-fringe people continue to believe that the forests belonging to them had unjustly been taken over by the former colonial government.

Another group of experts argue that the effects of centralized control over forest resources in the Indian subcontinent were: (i) diminished access to forest lands and products for resident communities, with serious consequences for their lifestyles, livelihood and security; (ii) enhancement of illegal use of forests because of restrictions; and iii) virtual extinction of the traditional practices and indigenous institutional mechanisms of forest use. Among the policy makers, therefore, it is increasingly realized drat without me willing participation of communities living in and around the forests, no programme of sustainable management can succeed, Such views are reflected in the multilateral agreements and declarations of recent years, such as, Agenda 21 (chapters 11 and 26) and Authoritative Statement of Forest Principals (para 5, 9a). However, participatory models are required more for Asian forests, most of which are located close to population centers and local encroachments for collection of fuel-wood, fodder or small timber are too rampant to be controlled.

The Forestry Sector Master Plan of Bangladesh (1993-2012) states: "In such situations, conventional forest management will not succeed   participatory forestry involving the villagers are the only recourse." The Plan regards the following definition of participation as acceptable: "In participatory forestry the participating farmers will be involved in planning, decision-making and implementation of all its activities. Accordingly, many countries have initiated a variety of participatory models in Latest management. Today no policy-maker talks of any development/resource management project without the ‘participation’ of local communities. The questions are: What kind of participation? How does participation take place? What is the policy-legal framework of participatory forest management?

With such a perspective, the present paper attempts to analyze the management of the Sundarbans in West Bengal, India The case of West Bengal as a learning experience is relevant and important for Bangladesh for several reasons: a) both areas share many similarities in historical experience and socio-economic conditions; b) West Bengal portion of the Sundarbans is a truncated part of one ecosystem, now severely degraded; c) 1-'Ds in both countries still bear the colonial legacy of management; d) the Bengal area is the most densely populated place in the world (except city states); and e) a model named joint forest management (IFM), initiated back in 1972 on a pilot basis is reportedly proving successful in regeneration of degraded state forests all over India including in the Sundarbans. Thus, the first part of this paper lays down a Conceptual Framework of participation, while the second part analyses the experience of participatory management of the Sundarbans in West Bengal, India.

Part I: Conceptual Framework if Participatory Resource Management
Erosion of customary rights over land and trees due to state-sponsored privatization or nationalization of natural resources is regarded as the real problem. In South Asia since the 1950s, local common property resources/regimes (CPR) have broken down not so much by population pressure as by inequitable privatization schemes. When Indian government authorities began to privatize well-functioning CPR systems in the name of clarifying ownership and helping the poor; the traditional village commons collapsed and the poorest households received only one-half to one-third the amount of land given to more prosperous households. Another Indian analyst argues that privatization of CPR has led to overuse of forests because of unavailability of common pasture, and the local rich have doubly benefited from such privatization - as owners of nearby lands, they gradually encroached into the adjacent public forest lands.

Such actions fit the CPR Tragedy Model (Fig.1), articulated by Garrett Hardin. It argues that individual rationality manifest in the form of maximizing benefits leads to collective tragedy It calls for a superior force in the form of private or state ownership and management. Accordingly some argue for private property rights to well-defined parcels of forest lands either through sale in the financial market or by lottery But the experience of some countries like Indonesia, Malaysia and the Philippines indicate that large private firms, guided by a profit-making motive, could not manage forests with an objective of long term sustainability.

Experiences also show that the so-called ‘effective hegemony’ imposed by government resource managers worsens the problem by undermining local users' responsibility to protect resources. This is vindicated by the realities in the stale forests of many countries including Bangladesh. In recent years, because of environmental degradation, state agencies in the developing world are tightening zoning and other centralized restrictions on land and resource use. If past experiences are any guide, such a renewed centralized control of resources under heavy biotic pressure is utterly misplaced.

But the other, Viability Model of CPR (Fig.1) is supported by the empirical research of Bromley, Cernea, Ostrom and others. Their studies show that many communities dependent on common resources, both in developed and developing countries, have devised and sustained informal/customary ways to control access to the resource and institute rules among the risers. The CPR tragedy model simply conflates "common property" with “open access" resources. To viability advocates, CPR management is a question of identifying the appropriate social and institutional arrangements at the community level. Michael Cernea (1989), senior adviser to the World Bank, pointed out:
"Resource degradation in the developing countries, while incorrectly attributed to common property systems’ intrinsically actually originates in the dissolution of local level institutional arrangements whose very purpose was to give rise to resource use patterns that were sustainable."

Communities with power to control some resources are seldom prone to destructive practices. Dangers arise when the rural elite or elite-backed governments take away local control. Incentives to conserve then disappear: Non-accountable government agencies, such as forest departments, irrigation bureaucracies and marketing boards often constitute the greatest single threat to secure local control by ordinary farmers and the landless. Agarwal thus argues:
"Whenever national bureaucracies have taken over management role, discharged by local communities, systems of traditional governance over natural resources have broken down, and local communities were alienated and environmental resources suffered.” 

Thus, Agenda 21 includes a Chapter on promoting `sustainable livelihoods' for the poor; and this builds on the positive experiences of many community-based initiatives in resource management. After spending about US $1.5 billion on forestry projects in Asia between 1979 and 1990, the World Bank admits that its actions "have had a negligible impact on borrower's forestry sectors as a whole." The Brundtland Report entitled Our Common Future argues, "Programs to preserve forest resources must start with the local people who are both victims and agents of destruction . . . They should be at the centre of integrated forest management, which is the basis of sustainable agriculture." The Report also acknowledged that achieving sustainable development (SD) requires a fundamental change in the way natural resources are owned, controlled and used.

This brings in the question of linkage between management regime and property rights on natural resources. Property can be regarded as a secure claim to a resource or its services. Property rights/regimes in natural resources exist in usually four forms (Fig.1):
a) Private property;
b) Open access resource, where legal rights are not clearly defined;
c) State property where the legal claim rests with the government, such as in land and forests; and
d) Common or communal property resources (CPR), where individuals have claims as members of recognized groups,

During the times of antiquity all natural resources belonged to the Crown or the Sovereign. The citizens, often in groups, were given the usufructs, a use right without legal ownership. During the industrial period, increased technological power and mobility created an open system in which resource substitution and importation

NRM & PR

 
Fig.1

 


















minimized the fears of scarcity, Resources were therefore perceived as being both absolutely and relatively abundant. During this period, according to O'Riordan (1985), social controls over resource appraisal and allocation gave way to laissez-faire and the freedom of rights of the individual. Competition set the rules and economic principles dominated the allocation process in the then-industrializing world. In the colonized world, the Western concept of rights of the individuals over that of the community was strengthened, as individuals began to buy/own formerly communal properties. Currently there is no problem with private property rights in general. However, there are serious problems with the last two categories, i.e. state property and CPR. Alienation of poor communities compounded the problem of government management, which falls to control encroachments from local and distant sources. Therefore, sustainable resource management is argued to be a function of cooperation at all levels. It is argued that this cooperation will sustain through 'effective` participation of local communities, who are the best guards against distant and more powerful encroachers.

People‘s Participation: Varied Interpretations
Participation, like SD, has become an umbrella term for a new approach to development intervention. A review of relevant literature in such disciplines as economics, political science and sociology presents a complex and confusing picture of the concept.

Disagreements occur as to what participation really means or how it should be realized. The fundamental split is between those who see participation as a means to an end, and those who advocate it as an end in itself. As a goal in itself, community participation is viewed by some as a necessity for individual and social well-being; others see it as a 'basic need by itself of men and women.’ Such views are related with the perceived inadequacies of the new democratic nation-states, where the newly-forming political institutions usually bypass the poor and marginalized populations. The democratization process in the South is dominated by the urban middle class, in cooperation with the rural elite. The latter have at times used democratic procedures to consolidate and extend local power. UNDP’s 1993 Human Development Report estimated that more than 90% of the global population is unable to exert a meaningful impact on economic, political and social functioning of societies they live in.

Therefore, participation is to be concerned with power; particularly to control resources and decision-making. Brazilian sociologist and dependency theorist FH Cardoso (who was elected President of Brazil) argued that participation ought to be linked to political activity in broader arenas, and not confined to small-scale, problem solving efforts. Attaining sustained participation thus requires major political change and decentralization, nut of administrative bureaucracy (as often is done), but of management of resources. Thus, what is needed first is economic democracy without which political democracy has no meaning for the poor and disenfranchised. The focus should be on socioeconomic empowerment through implementing land reforms, providing security of tenure, employment and support programmes, expansion of educational opportunities in rural areas etc. Once the poor as a group are sensitized enough about their condition, they can exert their voice in local and ultimately national-level decision-making.

Empirical studies by scholars of participatory development, such as Uphoff (1979), Oakley and Mars den (1984), Blair (1985), Ghazi (1994) and Medley (l986) show that state-initiated community participation was often meant for cooptation, political mobilization or clienteles. In most of the cases a top-down approach to development has remained essentially unchanged, So state-directed participation is regarded as a paradox, While the state now controls resources and the lives of its citizens to an extent previously unknown, it is naive to assume that the ruling elite readily agree to devolution of authority to the masses. Medley (1986) presents four types of state responses to participation, based on such criteria as state definition of what participation entails, or the degree to which it is willing to devolve power to local institutions: a) the anti-participatory mode (participatory initiatives are viewed by regimes as threats and are suppressed); b) the manipulative mode (participatory rhetoric is used by regimes for some ulterior motive); c) the incremental mode (regimes officially support participation, but policia are vaguely formulated and incrementally implemented); and d) the participatory mode (regimes create machinery for effective participation through devolution). These fonns are not definitive, and a state may fall between one or more categories at various points of time. A typology of participation can be seen in Table 1.


 



















However there is no agreed set of indicators for comparison of the participation processes. Political regimes greatly differ in the degree of participation they allow in the development process. Experiences in many developing countries indicate a trend of distorted implementation of policies because of a lack of accountability on the part of ruling elite, Therefore, to examine the process at the micro-level, participation has to be looked at through the questions that Norman Uphoff, a leading theoretician of participatory development, suggests: namely WHO participate, WHAT kind of participation takes place, and HOW it takes place. Then state responses to participation can be checked against the framework of the four participatory modes, mentioned before. Such an approach helps locate and explain the degree of fit between the policy framework and its implementation.

Table 2: Typology of Participation in Development Projects

Typology                                                                                                Characteristics of Each Type
1. Manipulative Participation                                                   Participation is simply a pretence, with “people's” representatives on official committees, but who are unelected and have no power.
2.Passive/Pseudo-Participation           People participate by being told what has                                                                                                                                                                                                                                                                                                                                                                                                                                                          been decided or has already happened. It involves unilateral announcements by an administration or project management without any listening to peop1e's responses, The information being shared belong only to external managers/ professionals.

3. Participation by Consultation                     People participate by being
consulted or by answering
questions. External agents define
problems & information gathering
process, and so control analysis.
Such a consultative process does
not concede any share in decision
making, and professionals are
under no obligation to take on
board people’s views.

4. Participation for Material                           People participate by contributing
Incentives                                                       resources, for example, labor; in
return for food, cash or other
material incentives. Farmers may
Incentives
provide land and labor, but are
involved in neither
experimentation nor the process of
learning. It is very common to see
this called participation, yet people
have no stake in prolonging
technologies or practices when the
incentives end.

5. Functional Participation                             Participation seen by external
agencies as a means to achieve
project goals, especially reduced
costs, People may participate by
forming groups to meet
predetermined objectives related to
the project. Such involvement may
be interactive and involve shared
decision-making, but tends to arise
only after external agents have
already made major decisions. At
worst, local people may still only
be co-opted to serve external goals.

6. Authentic/interactive                                  People participate in joint analysis,
Participation                                                   development of action plans and
formation or strengthening of
local institutions. Participation is
seen as a night, not just the means
to achieve project goals. The
process involves interdisciplinary
methodologies that seek multiple
perspectives and make use of
systematic and structured learning
processes. As groups take control
over local decisions and determine
how available resources are used,
they have a stake in sustaining the
structures/practices.

7. Spontaneous Participation/                         People participate by taking
Self -mobilization                                           initiatives independently of
external institutions to change the
system. They develop contacts with
external institutions for resources
and technical advice they need,
but retain control over how
resources are used. Self-
mobilization can spread if
governments and NGOs provide an
enabling framework of support.
Such self-initiated mobilization
may or may not challenge the
existing distribution of wealth and
power.
Source: adapted from Pretty; J.N., “Participatory Learning for Sustainable Agricultural,  World Development 23(8), 1995.

Part 11: Participatory Forest Management in West Bengal, India

Based on a policy of inclusion, many countries of Asia, Africa and Latin America have developed a variety of participatory models in forest management, These models can be grouped into the following broad typology:
1) Farm and homestead forestry
2) Group farm forestry as in West Bengal
3) Cooperative/Community woodlot, as in China and Korea
4) Joint forest management, as in India, Nepal and Indonesia
5) Management by indigenous communities/NGOs in Thailand, the Philippines and in some Latin American countries
6) Communal/private lease contracts, as in China or the Philippines
7) Collaborative forest management, as in Thailand or Indonesia (in this model, a triangular collaboration takes place among social scientists, FDs and local communities/NGOs)

As there is no universally accepted framework of the participation process, these models differ widely in their working dynamics. However; the model of joint forest management UTM) in West Bengal deserves particular mention. Informally initiated as a pilot protect in the Sal forest of Arabari, southwest West Bengal in 1972 by some forest officials, led by Dr Ajit K. Banerjee (then DFO of Silviculture, South), the model of JFM proved successful in regenerating the degraded Sal forests. The model was based on care (protection by villagers through social fencing) and share (usufructs including 25% of timber value). The state and federal governments formally approved the model in 1989 and 1990 respectively for nation-wide replication. Currently FDs of almost all Indian state governments have introduced JFM and  thousand of forest protection committees (FPCs) have been formed all over India But West Bengal leads me programme to date, with the extent of people’s involvement regarded as the highest, compared to the rest of India. This leading status of West Bengal in}FM can be discerned from the following criteria: a) Regeneration of forests; b) Restitution of biodiversity; c) Income generation; d) Cost-effectiveness; and e) Acceptance of JFM at the micro, national and international levels, Currently, the FPCs in West Bengal protect an area over half the state forest land. The fact that forests are protected and regenerated better through people’s participation, compared to traditional custodial management, has been widely recognized. Together with its rapid spread across India, other countries are applying JFM in their own ways. In 1992 the FPCs of West Bengal collectively received the Paul Getty international award for their contribution to forest regeneration. In the mid-90s, the World Bank had extended a project loan of US $54 million to finance the promotion of IPM in West Bengal, a state ruled by a left-front government (LFG) since 1977.

Status of the West Bengal Part of the Sundarbans

In the late 19th century the total area of the Sundarbans comprised about 19,500 sq kms of which the Indian/West Bengal part was 9,650 sq kms. Currently the area under Reserve Forest is 4.2 sq kms and the rest of the area is reclaimed and inhabited. Over 2,585 sq kms of forest area, the Sundarbans tiger Reserve Forest had been created in 1975 and the rest was demarcated for forestry activities. There are three wildlife sanctuaries, namely Sajnekhali, Haliday Island and Lothian Island and one National park within the Sundarbans Biosphere Reserve area. Administrative boundary of the Sundarbans passes through two districts i.e. north 24-Parganas and south 24- Parganas covering 19 Blocks - 6 under the former and 13 under the latter

Socio-Economic Status of People in the Sundarbans

Over four-fifths of the people living in the Sundarbans are dependent on agriculture on reclaimed land which bear mostly single crop of paddy. Besides agriculture, other occupations are finishing and pisciculture, honey collection and wood-cutting. Some 50% of agricultural laborers are landless. And 44% of total population belongs to Schedule Caste and Schedule Tribes. As a result, the level of literacy and per capita income are much lower in the Sundarbans than in other parts of West Bengal. The communication is also very poor and most of the areas are inaccessible. Though some of the points are linked with Calcutta by few metal roads, communication in this area dissected by the network of numerous streams and canals is dependent mainly on boats and motor launches.
Protection/Conservation: Administrative Measures and Infrastructural Facilities:

1.             One Director in the rank of CCF is in overall charge of Sundarbans Biosphere Reserve (SBR) under which comes the Sundarbans Tiger Reserve.
2.             There is a State-level Steering Committee for the Sundarbans Mangroves and Biosphere Reserve Management` constituted to guide and oversee the Biosphere Reserve Program and its activities. Chief Secretary Govt. of West Ben al, is the Chairman of this Committee and the Representative of  the Government of India Principal Chief Conservator of Forests, Director of SBR, a number of specialists, representatives of NGOs and Shabhadhipatis of both north and south 24 Parganas Zilla Parishads are members of this Committee.
3              There is a Monitoring Sub-Committee to monitor the physical and financial performances of all projects under the Mangrove Biosphere Reserve Program and to assess the impact of various components of the projects including generation of employment, economic upliftment of the people along with their attitudes and acceptance of the schemes.
4.             There is also a Research Sub-Committee under the state-level Steering Committee to identify the research areas concerning social adversities, study on impact of pollution, effect of traditional system and development of more productive System.

Major Central and sore Projects
Important on-going schemes are:
A             Centrally sponsored Schemes are:
i) Establishment of SBR
ii) Conservation and Management of Sundarbans mangroves
iii) Integrated Afforestation and Eco-Development Project.
B.            West Bengal Forestry Project (World Bank-funded).
C.            Area-Oriented Fuel wood and Fodder Program (50% Centrally sponsored Scheme).

JFM and Eco-Development of People in and around the Sundarbans

Traditional form management and mere policing were found to be insufficient to conserve mangrove forests and their biodiversity SBR was, therefore, created with the main thrust on socioeconomic development activities with conservation and ensuring people’s participation in the process through mass awareness building and motivation. Following the success of JFM through Forest Protection Committees (FPCs) in the fringe villages in other pans of West Bengal, the same system has also been introduced in SBR area While forming the FPCS, stress has been given to include all the families in the villages taking one member from each family with the prevision of joint membership for each household (husband being a member; wife becomes automatically a member).

As provided in the Government Order of 1989, the members of FPCs will be entitled to 25% of net sale proceeds of final harvesting of plantations/forests and 25% of the intermediate yields from coppicing, multiple shoot-cutting and thinning and collection of fallen twigs, grass its, flowers, seeds etc. For socioeconomic development of the people, a package of eco-development programme which includes Mari culture, aquaculture, bee-keeping, farm forestry, horticulture, distribution of smokeless Chula, use of solar energy for generating electricity, vocational training, health services, veterinary services, etc. are being implemented. With the economic upliftment of the people in and around the Sundarbans, the buffer population will help protect the mangrove forests and their eco-system from the biotic interference. This will also minimize the age-old man-animal conflict. Many FPCs comprising of villagers have already been formed and recognized within the areas of 24-pargarras.

Pisciculture: Under SBR programme, ponds close to the bank of rivers have been excavated at government cost and each such pond is being handed over to a group often beneficiaries in the villages as per recommendations of local Pantalets. Importance has also been attached to popularize culture of edible oysters and crabs.

Honey Collection & Apiculture: On an average 60,000 kgs of honey are extracted from the Sundarbans every year through the honey- collectors and FD takes the honey as well as wax from them at fixed tariff and arrange for sale of filtered honey after processing in the Departmental Filtering Unit at Sealdah. About a thousand of families earn their livelihood through collection of honey from the Sundarbans forests.

Apiculture (bee-keeping) is now gradually becoming popular and necessary training is imparted under the SBR programme. Apiary- boxes have been distributed among the villagers as per recommendation of local Penchants and these are supplementing the income of the beneficiaries.

Timber & Other Forest Products - Their Uses: At present, matured natural forests are extracted for timber and fuel-wood on a rotation

Smokeless Chullah & Use of Solar Energy: Such chullahs are very useful to combat the win problems - scarcity of fuel-wood as well as pressure on conventional energy sources. More than 14,000 chullahs have been distributed to the villagers within SBR by the mid-90s. Trial on use of solar energy for generation of electricity particularly for illumination purpose proved to be useful in some areas within SBR. Important locations within the STR area are also illuminated at night by use of solar energy So far; several hundred points within the SBR have been brought under solar energy technology.

Vocational Training: To generate scope for self-employment and help earn supplementary income, the SBR wing organizes vocational training for the villagers in the Sundarbans area on Pisciculture, Poultry Apiculture and Horticulture.

Educational Trips: Villagers from fringe areas are taken to the forests of Sundarbans and other parts of West Bengal to make them acquainted with various aspects of JFM and status of forest protection there. Trips are also arranged for students from different schools/colleges for their exposure to nature and diverse flora and fauna of the Sundarbans.

Awareness: With a view to expose the villagers and students of schools and colleges to various aspects of JFM and conversation of forests and wildlife, video shows in different areas on forestry and wildlife are arranged by different units of SBR. Two centers - one at Sajnekhali and another at Bhagabatpur have also been established keeping these objectives in View

Role of Women: Women folk in the Sundarbans play a significant role along with men in earning their livelihood, in IFM, wives have the joint membership in FP(1s along with their husbands. Women groups are also taken to villages for their motivation and awareness through dialogues, meetings and conventions. Training programmes suitable for women are also organized.

Health & Veterinary Service: FD in collaboration with the Department of Health & Family Planning has started coordinated health-service programme to fill up the gap and periodic health-service camps are organized in remote villages taking advantage of available infrastructural facilities of SBR and knowledge of foresters about the people and the locality Health service camps are also organized in the villages with NGOs, Besides the necessary assistance from the  Directorate of Veterinary for extending such services in the villages, the STR project has also veterinary experts to serve the local needs.
Coordination with Other GOs: It is an uphill task for the SBR wing of FD with limited resources to fulfill the total objectives of Biosphere Programme to coordinate the three elements of Eco-restoration, Eco- conservation and Eco-development. Therefore, coordination is maintained among the departments of Agriculture, Irrigation, Health & Family Planning, Animal Resource Development, Education, Fisheries, Science & Technology and Department of Sundarbans Affairs. Sundarbans Development Board has been taking part in the execution of substantial work of afforestation, soil conservation and socio-economic development under the SBR. Calcutta Port Trust is also associated with afforestation and research programme of the SBR in the vicinity of their working zone.

Role of NGOs in SBR: Many NGOs are involved in the SBR programme, but they work in partnership with the FD. The NGOs do not control many resources independent of the government, either in the West Bengal or elsewhere in India.

A Synthesis: It was proposed in the framework that the experience of West Bengal would be checked against the four modes of state responses to participation. Looking through these lenses, it may be deduced that West Bengal falls in between the incremental and participatory modes. State policy has legitimized community participation in forest management. Community needs have been given preference to industrial needs in forest products by the Forest Policy of 1988 (a reversal of prior policies). The policy laid out some modalities of implementation. The democratically-elected left-front government initiated important structural changes, such as a) land reforms and share-cropper` rights, b) effective Panchayati Raj, and c) integrated implementation of rural development programmes, led by the increasingly representative local leaderships. The LFG power base commands the required autonomy independent of the vested, propertied classes to pursue reforms and policies within a social- democratic framework that favors the poor. However; it must be mentioned that the LFG did choose to ride the winning horse of JFM, led by the FD. But the LFG policies helped sustain the programme of JFM.

The FD bureaucracy as a whole appears committed to the programme, as evident from their activities, departmental restructuring and initiatives for attitudinal changes through training of officers, with NGO assistance. The FD’s attempt to maximize employment benefits to the FPC members through tuning their operations during the lean season, and coordinating other programmes in the fringe areas are further evidence to their commitment. From discussions with the FD officials of West Bengal, it was clear that in a traditionally hierarchical, structured bureaucracy such as the FD, initiatives for effective participatory management have to come from within the bureaucracy itself. Because as an organization it develops a vested interest to maintain its own value systems and becomes resistant to outside forces/influences coming in. Such a thesis is borne out by other country experiences, such as the US Forest Service.

The above factors can be viewed as elements of a participatory mode. But it contains contradictions: rather than empowering the FPCs, it strengthens die state, as well as the party in power The problem is: the core feature of participatory mode - the devolution of power and decision-making down to the local community organization, the FPC - is still missing. The amendment to the state government order of 1990 has expanded the FPC role from mere protection’ to various activities, but die latter formulation is vague, and findings from the field indicate that all those activities pertain to 'responsibilities' only on FD terms. The federal circular also stipulates community participation in the planning process. As seen, the FD staffs carry out all such activities. With the provision of registration of FPCs only with the FD, the former even does not have any legal status. Tire FPCs are yet to play the role of an actor:

Although the LFG drive for political mobilization of the rural masses through national and local party institutions has achieved sustained electoral victories since 1977, the accumulated political sensitization and empowerment are not yet reflected in the FD-FPC equation. The power o the local government representatives regarding die FPC activities is still recommendatory in nature. This shows either the regime is not yet sure of the efficacy and viability of local level devolution in JFM programme, or that participation is not taken by the political regime as a goal in itself, or drat the still developing participatory political-administrative processes are yet to wrest control in directing the programme implementation.

As a result, the government muddles through in its implementation of die programme, changing its orders in an incremental fashion, despite the fact that spontaneous participation of villagers in the FPC programme anti-dated the government approval. With the current level of participation and its functioning, JFM might be sustained the way it is so long as the LFG remains in power since under it, the local power structure includes the poor low-caste and tribal population, Buta change of government in West Bengal, headed by Congress or Bhartya Janata Party in future may change the balance again in favor of the propertied class. In that case, &e future of JFM with its current dependence on extra-community forces and levers of power for functioning does not augur well. Even after years of functioning, the programme fails to develop a community leadership, able to take charge, independent of the regime in power, or the local foresters’ patronizing role, As a further setback, the Indian Forest Act appears to be a new brake on JFMs march forward: its restrictive provisions may further disempowered the communities, and strengthen bureaucracy and the state. In any case, with all its drawbacks, _IFM can still be regarded as the initial Slip towards the larger frame of community control and management of a vital natural resource like forests.






0 comments:

Post a Comment